Media  Global Economy  2014.04.03

The Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement and Revitalizing Agriculture

IIST e-Magazine on November 29, 2013("The TPP and Agricultural Revitalization" Part 1 of 5)

 Participation in the TPP will destroy Japanese agriculture, according to some parties. Is Japanese agriculture really so fragile? In an era of population decline, will protecting a shrinking domestic market with tariffs be sufficient to enable agriculture to survive?


 The Liberal Democratic Party and the Diet agricultural committees have adopted resolutions urging the government to have Japan's rice, wheat, beef and pork, dairy products and sugar exempted from tariff elimination under the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) agreement and to leave the negotiating table if unable to do so. Diet members apparently equate the national interest with maintaining tariffs.

 However, what those tariffs are really protecting are high domestic prices for agricultural products-in other words, food prices. For example, to protect the high price of domestically-produced wheat, which accounts for only 14 percent of total consumption, tariffs are levied on the foreign wheat that accounts for the other 86 percent, forcing expensive bread and udon noodles upon consumers.

 In the case of rice, the government has used some 500 billion yen of taxpayers' money to have farmers reduce the acreage used for rice cultivation. As a result, supply has been reduced and prices boosted for the Japanese diet staple of rice, on top of which consumers have paid out over 500 billion yen. The total public burden entailed in producing 1.8 trillion yen's worth of rice is more than one trillion yen. High rice prices too are being protected by tariffs.

 Many politicians opposed the consumption tax hike on the grounds that it would make food more expensive for poor people-yet bolstering food prices with tariffs and reduced rice acreage is apparently for the national good.

 The United States has shifted to a policy of protecting agriculture not with high prices but with direct payments out of government coffers. Not only has this brought down prices, but an amount three times the size of the farming budget is put into a food stamp program for low-income earners. The US policy is logically consistent even from the perspective of consumer protection.

 Even if removing tariffs in Japan brought down food prices, we could avoid impacting farmers by following the US in using government funds to cover the difference between domestic and international prices, and consumers would benefit. The agricultural sector argues that the great disparity between domestic and foreign prices would require massive government spending, but this is tantamount to admitting that a huge burden is currently being imposed on consumers. As in the above case of wheat, consumers are also paying high prices for imported foreign wheat, so the consumer burden is even larger again. Just covering the difference between domestic agricultural product prices and international prices with direct payments would benefit consumers hugely by removing the consumer burden for not only domestic produce but also foreign farm products.

140403_yamashita_e.gif

 However, to the extent that, unlike the US, Japan maintains its policy of protecting farmers with domestic prices that are more expensive than international prices, tariffs will be required. No other country is seeking as many TPP exemptions as Japan. At the end of the day, the Japanese government will probably negotiate to keep rice at least off the table.

 The underlying assumption is that Japanese agriculture's small scale makes it unable to compete with US and Australian agriculture. In terms of the amount of land operated per farm, if we put Japan at 1, the EU would be 6, the US 75 and Australia 1,309. Other things being equal, the greater the scale, the lower the cost. However, scale is not the only important factor. While the US is the world's largest exporter of agricultural produce, its farmland is only one-seventeenth the size of Australia's. Crop types and crop yield per unit area of land cultivation both differ according to soil fertility. Barren soil means that most of Australia's agriculture comprises cattle-grazing on plains, whereas corn, soybean and wheat production dominates in the US.

 In addition, in agricultural produce as in cars, there are major quality differences. In Hong Kong, Koshihikari rice produced in Japan fetches a price 1.6 times higher than Koshihikari grown in California, and 2.5 times higher than Chinese Koshihikari. Apparently, only one percent of the world trade volume in rice--or only 300,000 of 300 billion tons--can compete on quality with the eight million tons of rice produced in Japan.

 Moreover, the argument that Japanese agriculture cannot compete with the US and other countries assumes that the elimination of tariffs is accompanied by no other government action. The agricultural scale of the EU might be 10 percent that of the US and 0.5 percent that of Australia, yet thanks to high productivity and direct government payments, the EU can export grain. The wheat yield of the United Kingdom is five times higher than in Australia.

 Even if food prices in Japan fell as a consequence of tariff elimination, farmers would not be impacted if government funds were used to cover the price difference. The difference in price between Japanese rice and the rice produced in China and California has shrunk to around 30 percent. Even under current conditions, more farmers are exporting rice. Because the price differential between Japan and other countries is shrinking, contrary to the argument of the Japanese agricultural sector, only relatively minor direct payments would need to be made.

 By shrinking production and pushing up prices, the rice acreage reduction policy has robbed Japanese rice of its competitiveness. The per-unit quantity cost is calculated by dividing cost per unit of land by crop yield, so if the yield rises, the cost goes down. However, since the government brought in its rice acreage reduction policy to constrain production, farmers have given up on selective breeding programs designed to boost crop yield. Currently, Japan's average crop yield is 40 percent less than California's. In addition, because rice prices are high, even micro-farmers with high costs have kept farming. Because these micro-farmers aren't making their land available, farmers whose main source of income comes from farming haven't been able to amalgamate enough land to expand their scale of production.

 If we dropped our rice acreage reduction policy and rice prices went down accordingly, micro-farmers whose main source of income comes from other occupations would lease out their land. Making direct payments only to full-time farmers would boost their capacity to pay land rents and farmland would concentrate in their hands. The rice production cost for farms of 15 or more hectares is 6,378 yen per 60 kilograms. If abandoning our rice acreage reduction policy brought Japanese rice yields up to Californian levels, the production cost would drop by 28 percent to 4,556. That would be less than half the national average of 9,478 yen.

 Even if we protect the domestic market from foreign agricultural produce using steep tariffs, the graying of society and population decline will see that market shrink. To sustain and boost agriculture, we need to create export markets. However, no matter how hard farmers work to cut costs, they won't be able to export if our trading partners have high tariffs in place. If Japan is not going to participate proactively in trade liberalization negotiations like the TPP that do away with trading partners' tariffs, Japanese agriculture will simply proceed with its assisted suicide.

 If we abandon the rice acreage reduction policy and bring the domestic rice price down to 8,000 yen, and if the Chinese rice price rises to 13,000 yen in response to higher labor costs in the Chinese rural sector and yuan appreciation, farmers will export, in turn lifting the domestic price. Production will expand, and farmers will be able to more than double their current rice income.

 Some producers are exporting rice even at the current price. Given the world-leading quality of our rice, boosting productivity and introducing direct payments to achieve price competitiveness would grant us a decisive advantage.